Designing coordinating contracts for the consignment channel: Integrating manufacturer-greening and retailermarketing efforts

Dinh Anh Phan, Hoa T. L. Vo, Hong Quang Duong/ MICA 2018 Proceedings  
International Conference on Marketing in the Connected Age (MICA-2018), October 6th, 2018  
Danang City, Vietnam  
Designing Coordinating Contracts for the Consignment  
Channel: Integrating Manufacturer-Greening and Retailer-  
Marketing Efforts  
Dinh Anh Phana*, Hoa T. L. Vob, Hong Quang Duongc  
aUniversity of Economics The University of Danang, 71 Ngu Hanh Son Street, Danang City, Vietnam  
aPhD Student, IGR-IAE, University of Rennes 1, France  
bAssociate Professor in Production and Operations Management at IGR-IAE, University of Rennes 1, France  
cFPT School of Business and Technology, Vietnam  
A B S T R A C T  
In this paper, we study the sustainable coordination of a consignment channel that arises due to simultaneous  
consideration of Greening and Marketing initiatives undertaken by channel agents. We investigate a green  
channel where the manufacturer (M) is responsible for greening and the retailer (R) undertakes marketing  
efforts. Therefore, the market demand is affected by retail price, R’s marketing and M’s greening efforts. Using  
M-led Stackelberg game to model the decision-making of the two firms in the channel, we analyze the  
decentralized channel under our four proposed sharing contracts, namely Revenue Production cost sharing  
(RP), Revenue Production cost and Marketing cost sharing (RPM), Revenue Production cost and Greening  
cost sharing (RPG), and Revenue Production cost Marketing cost and Greening cost sharing (RPMG). For  
each sharing contract, we first consider the scenario that the sharing fraction is determined by either R or M  
who dominates the green channel and then envisage the possibility of negotiation between R and M on the  
sharing fraction which forms the basis of division of costs and revenues. Our analytical results show that the  
cooperation between M and R via sharing contracts improves the greening level of the products and the overall  
profitability of channel. In addition, both M and R get higher profits in the coordination state. From managerial  
insights, our research could help channel managers to improve greening level as well as the overall  
performance of channel.  
Keywords: marketing effort; consignment channel; green channel; coordinating contract  
1. Introduction  
The development of industrial technology and the focus of manufacturers on their growth and profit had  
adverse effects on the environment and society (Hsueh, 2015) and considering Greening within supply chain  
(channel) management has become an inevitable requirement for improving the competitiveness of  
manufacturers (Xiao and Yang, 2008). In recent times, green supply chain management is becoming increasingly  
attention among scholars and practitioners who are integrating environmentally sound choices into supply chain  
management research and practice (Yenipazarli, 2017; Babbar et al., 2017). From business practice, increasingly  
regulatory pressures and as well as rising public environmental protection awareness have forced the M giants to  
work with upstream and downstream companies to build green supply chains (Sancha et al., 2016). The  
manufacturers are asked to provide evidence of their operations meeting relevant environmental requirements  
and, in some cases evidence of ISO14001 certification (Swami et al., 2013). Therefore, M can invest funds for  
new product research and development (R&D) to develop green products (Song and Gao, 2018) that reduce  
environmental impact of production process and meet the increasing consumer demand for these products. As an  
* Corresponding author. E-mail address: dinhanhdhkt@gmail.com  
382  
Dinh Anh Phan, Hoa T. L. Vo, Hong Quang Duong/ MICA 2018 Proceedings  
example, Adidas, a leading M of athletic wear, uses Eco-Grip technology to reduce harmful substances from  
materials used in manufacturing to minimize the manufacturing impact on environment. Similarly, World's  
largest beverage company Coca-Cola has made significant efforts in measuring and reducing its carbon  
footprints. In another example, PepsiCo mandates her suppliers to implement green technology to reduce the  
carbon footprint in their businesses. An increase in greening performance may lead to greater market demand but  
requires higher greening investment cost (Raj et al., 2018). Therefore, firms are only willing to adopt green  
technology if they enhance their profitability (Yang et al., 2017). In addition to M’s greening efforts, R who are  
more likely to face the public directly can exploit the sales channel to promote the market demand and boost  
sales (Wang and Hu, 2011). R’s sales channel includes different types of “marketing efforts” such as local  
advertising, on-site shopping assistance, rebates and post-sales service. However, these activities may constitute  
a significant portion of firm’s operating expenses (Xiao et al. 2005). As a result, if the M does not provide  
sufficient incentives, then R will have no motivation to enhance marketing effort level (Krishnan et al., 2004).  
It is also well known that when the channel member’s decisions on efforts are made separately and each party  
pays the associated costs of efforts to maximize their own profit, these strategies lead to a suboptimal level of  
efforts which may lower total profit of the whole channel. In the past decades, the issues of coordinating the  
green channel have received a great deal of research attention since it improves the profit both of the channel and  
of the individual channel member. Readers may refer to Raj et al. (2018) for a summary of the reviewed  
literature in the context of green supply chain (channel) management literature. Coordinating contracts provide  
incentives to induce channel members to behave in ways that are best for the whole channel while maximizing  
their own profit. This situation leads to a coordination of the channel. However, some coordinating contracts only  
reach the cooperation state (Pareto improvement) where the channel members are better off with the coordinating  
contract than any other different contracts (Chakraborty et al., 2015). In this paper, we propose an effective  
contract to coordinate the green channel through the combination of revenue-sharing and cost-sharing contracts  
and based on two common channel practices: consignment channel and Vendor Managed Inventory (VMI).  
Under the VMI system complemented by a consignment contract (VMI-CC), the vendor (i.e., M) manages the  
R's inventory levels and makes periodic replenishment decisions in terms of quantity and frequency (Wong et al,  
2009) while retaining ownership of the inventory (Chen et al. 2010). VMI-CC has been adopted by many  
industries such as personal computer and automobile. Readers may refer to Chen et al. (2010) for more examples  
of the VMI-CC. The coordination of a green channel using a revenue - sharing contract has been widely studied  
in the literature. Qian and Guo (2014) developed a revenue-sharing bargaining model between an Energy Service  
Company (ESCO) and an Energy-Using Organization (EU). Their research show that the greater the probability  
of adverse circumstances is, the higher is the revenue share (of the EU) and the more disadvantageous is the  
ESCO’s position in the game. Arani et al. (2016) proposed a mixed revenue-sharing option contract to coordinate  
the channel and modeled that using a game theoretic approach. Song and Gao (2018) established a green channel  
game model with two kinds of revenue-sharing contracts: the retailer-led- and the bargaining- revenue sharing  
contract. Their results proved that the revenue-sharing contracts can effectively improve the greening level of the  
products and the overall profitability of the channel. Besides, the cost-sharing contract has recently been used in  
coordinating a green channel (Ghosh and Shah., 2015; Arda., 2017; Raj et al., 2018). However, no study has  
addressed the coordination issues in a consignment channel with the presence of both M’s greening and R’s  
marketing efforts. Therefore, in this paper, we examine the problem of designing coordinating contract for a  
green consignment channel, focusing on how to share the channel’s revenue and costs between the channel  
members to achieve the best performance for such a channel. For doing this, we propose four kinds of sharing  
contracts namely RP, RPM, RPG, RPMG which are based on the combination of revenue-sharing and cost-  
sharing contract in VMI-CC. We study the efficiency of each sharing contract in a two-echelon channel where  
the market demand is affected by retail price, R’s marketing and M’s greening effort. In this context, we model  
the decision-making of the two firms in the decentralized channel as the M-Stackelberg game and carry out  
equilibrium analysis with consideration of wholesale price contract (WP) and four kinds of sharing contracts. We  
use the results of decentralized channel under WP as a benchmark for the evaluation of channel cooperation with  
the sharing contracts. We also develop a corresponding model for centralized channel and use the optimal results  
to investigate channel coordination.  
Our work contributes to the extant literature in two folds. First, we develop an analytical model dealing with  
channel coordination issues for the different decisions impacting on the channel performance including not only  
the operational choices (quantity, price) and marketing decisions of the firms but also the green channel  
management. Therefore, our study address a business practices which so far has not been studied. Secondly, we  
propose the coordination schemes for the green consignment channel through the combination of revenue-  
sharing and cost-sharing contracts under VMI system.  
This paper is organized as follows: after this introductory section, we describe the problem setting with  
notations and assumptions in Section 2. Section 3 focuses on analyzing a centralized model and a decentralized  
model. In Section 4, we analyze the impact of bargaining power on the implementation of sharing contract and  
the channel performance. We next conduct numerical studies to validate the proposed models in Section 5. A  
383  
Dinh Anh Phan, Hoa T. L. Vo, Hong Quang Duong/ MICA 2018 Proceedings  
summary of the findings, the managerial insights, and suggested directions for future research are described in  
the last section. To save place, all of proof, some tables and analyses are put in the Appendix and available upon  
request from the authors  
2. Model formulation  
We consider a two-echelon distribution channel consisting of a M (he) and a R (she), in which M produces the  
green product and sells it through R who then sells the products to the final consumers. We assume that the  
consumers are sensitive towards environment friendly characteristic of a product as well as marketing efforts  
undertaken by R. We consider a deterministic linear demand function faced by a R in the market as follows: 퐷 =  
푎 − 푏푝 + 푒 + , 푎 > 0, 푏 > 0, > 0, > 0 and a-bc>0 are assumed for the demand function, where, a is  
overall market potential, b is price sensitivity, p is retail price, is greening level of product, e is marketing  
effort level, and are consumer sensitivity to greening and marketing effort levels respectively. (In Table 1,  
we present all relevant notations used in this paper). This type of demand function form has been widely used to  
incorporate the price, marketing and green effort impacting on the demand (Ma et al, 2013; Ghosh and Shah,  
2015; Arda, 2017; Raj et al., 2018). Here, the demand is decreasing in the retail price, increasing in both the R’s  
Marketing effort and product’s greening level. We further assume a quadratic functions to formulate R’s  
marketing and M’s green product R&D costs. The cost of green product R&D is entirely borne by M and is  
represented by 2/2 where > 0 is the green investment parameter (Banker et al., 1998; Song and Gao, 2018).  
Similarly, the cost of the marketing efforts at level e is 휂푒2/2 where 휂 > 0. This type of marketing cost function  
has been widely used in the literature (Krishnan et al., 2004; Ma et al, 2013). Assumption of cost nonlinearity  
represents the diminishing rate of returns for greening and marketing related activities. We also assume that both  
M and R possess full and symmetric information regarding costs and demand.  
The trade between M and R can be either a WP or a sharing contract. We define a sharing contract as being  
the combination of the revenue-sharing and cost-sharing between M and R embedded in the VMI-CC. Under  
such a contract, M retains the ownership of the consignment stock, decides on the retail price and manages the  
inventory at R (i.e., decides on stocking quantity). The sharing contract also specifies the sharing parameters to  
allocate the channel’s costs and revenue. For simplicity, we assume in our original model that the same sharing  
terms for revenue are used to share the costs. Therefore, in our proposed sharing contracts, if one kind of cost is  
shared, the fraction of cost sharing is equal to that of revenue sharing and we call it the sharing fraction for short.  
Further, we will extend our model using different sharing parameters for efforts costs. Under a sharing contract,  
the decision on the level of sharing fraction has to be made before deciding on the level of efforts meaning that M  
and R are engaged in a long-term commitment to share their costs and revenues. By contrast, the sharing fraction  
would have no impact on M’s greening and R’ marketing efforts. Therefore, when firms determine the level of  
their efforts, they know the share of investment cost on efforts will be undertaken by the other firm and their  
decision on the effort level would accommodate this sharing fraction. Once the investment in effort has been  
made, the upfront cost is divided between M and R according to this sharing fraction. As a consequence, R is free  
to determine the marketing effort level and M is free to determine the product’s greening level to maximize their  
own profit under the sharing contract. In particular, we propose the following four kinds of sharing contract to  
coordinate a green channel:  
Contract RP: The revenue and Production cost sharing contract  
Contract RPM: The revenue - Production cost and Marketing cost sharing contract  
Contract RPG: The revenue - Production cost and Greening cost sharing contract  
Contract RPMG: The revenue - Production cost - Marketing cost and Greening cost sharing contract  
In the RP contract, the inventory at R is owned by M, R does not pay M upon receipt of the stocks (i.e., green  
products) but shares the sales revenue on units sold. For each unit of any sold stock, R keeps a fraction (0, 1)  
of the revenue for herself and shares a fraction 1 − of her revenue with M, and R incurs a fraction of  
production cost for each unit of stock.  
In the RPM contract, R keeps a fraction (0, 1) of her revenue, incurs a fraction of production cost for  
each unit of stock and M is willing to bear a fraction 1 − of R’s marketing cost.  
In the RPG contract, R keeps a fraction (0, 1) of her revenue, incurs a fraction of production cost for  
each unit of stock and R is willing to share a fraction of the M's upfront cost of greening investment.  
In the RPMG contract, R keeps a fraction (0, 1) of her revenue, incurs a fraction of production cost for  
each unit of stock and R and M share their costs of marketing and greening with each other according to a  
fraction , i.e., R absorbs a fraction of the M’s greening cost while M absorbs a fraction 1 − of R’s  
marketing cost.  
384  
Dinh Anh Phan, Hoa T. L. Vo, Hong Quang Duong/ MICA 2018 Proceedings  
Table 1. Notations used.  
Notations  
Explanation  
Notations  
Explanation  
p
w
Unit retail price  
M’s wholesale price  
Product’s greening level  
Coefficient of greening effort cost  
Indicator of firm, i=m (M), r (R)  
Indicator of the sharing contract, j=RP,  
RPM, RPG, RPMG  
The optimal decisions for centralized  
channel  
The optimal decisions for decentralized  
channel under WP  
The optimal decisions for decentralized  
channel under sharing contract  
M’s, R’s and channel’s profit under WP  
i
j
(푝, 푒, )  
e
c
a
R's marketing effort level  
Unit production cost for M  
Market scale parameter  
(푝, 푒, 푊푃  
)
(푝, 푒, ):  
, , 푃  
, , 푗  
b
Price elasticity of the demand  
Consumer sensitivity to  
marketing effort  
M’s, R’s and channel’s profit under  
sharing contract j  
Consumer sensitivity to green  
improvements  
Coefficient of marketing effort  
cost  
Centralized channel’s profit  
c  
Sharing fraction  
3. Modeling centralized and decentralized channels  
3.1. The centralized channel model  
We first investigate the integrated channel which is considered as a single system operating under a global  
optimization strategy. In this setup, all relevant decisions are taken by a central planner who possesses all the  
relevant information. The central planner decides the optimal retail price, production quantity, greening level,  
and marketing effort level for the entire channel. Therefore, the optimization problem of the central planner is  
given by  
2
2
(
)
max (. ) = 푝 − 퐷 − 휂푒 /2  /2  
(1)  
,,  
From the problem of (1), we impose a restriction of 푏 > 훾2/2and 휅 > where= 휂휆2/(2푏휂 − 훾2) to  
ensure the Hessian matrix of Πc is a negative definite. The same expression of this condition is presented by 0 <  
2/휂 + 휆2/휅 < 2. Under this restriction, the profit of the centralized channel is jointly concave in p, e, and ,  
therefore, the optimal decisions of retail price , marketing effort level , and product greening level can be  
obtained through the first order optimality conditions.The results of optimal decisions are listed in Table 2 (in the  
following section). Substituting (푝, 푒, )into Eq. (1), we obtain the optimal profit of the centralized channel  
and present it in Table 3. From the optimal results: If market demand is not influenced by marketing efforts, then  
휆 = 0 and 0, the channel turns into a greening only channel.Under such a scenario, we can calculate the  
optimal values for a green channel using the limit 0. Similarly, if market demand is not influenced by  
greening efforts, then 0 and =0, the channel turns into a marketing only channel. In this case, we can  
determine the optimal values for a marketing channel using the limit 0. If market demand is neither greening  
nor marketing, then 휆 = 0 and =0, we can obtain the optimal values for a channel without efforts using the  
limit 0 and 0.We can also observe from the generalized results that the centralized channel orders more,  
earns more profit, makes higher greening level and marketing level with a higher consumer sensitivity to  
2
(
)
marketing and greening efforts.We further find that > 푙푖= 푎 − 푏/4푏 under the concavity  
condition of profit function. From this expression, the profit ofa0g,ree0n centralized channel is higher than that of  
its profit only counterpart. This finding indicates that if the consumers are willing to pay higher for green  
products and marketing effort, the firms will have motivations to invest more in green products and marketing  
efforts.  
3.2. Decentralized channel under WP  
In a decentralized channel, the channel members make their own decisions based on their own costs to  
maximize their own profits, but the decision making results are mutually influential. In a decentralized channel  
under WP contract, we model the decision-making problems of the two channel members as a M-led Stackelberg  
game (MS) in which the M takes the initiative and R as the follower1. The dynamic game order is as follows:  
firstly M determines the greening level of products and the wholesale price w. Subsequently, R determines the  
marketing effort level e, the retail price p and uses an order quantity equal to demand D to maximize her profit.  
To obtain the optimal decisions and firm-level profits in equilibrium, we use backward induction method to solve  
385  
Dinh Anh Phan, Hoa T. L. Vo, Hong Quang Duong/ MICA 2018 Proceedings  
this sequential move game. We begin by characterizing the R’s best-response function. For a given {w,}, R’s  
problem is max = (푝 − 푤)퐷 − 휂푒2/2. Based on the R’s best response, M’s problem can be stated as  
follows: max,푊푃 = (푤 − )퐷 − 2/2. The equilibrium results for WP contract are presented in Tables 2 and  
,  
3. Some algebraic calculations verify that: />2 and /푒>2. These results indicate that in a WP  
contract, optimal greening and marketing effort levels are less than half of the corresponding values for a  
centralized channel. This finding suggests that the channel agents need to puts higher efforts in greening and  
marketing effort in a decentralized channel to get more profit. We further observe that /c < 3/4. This  
observation implies that the double marginalization problem and suboptimal level of efforts of WP contract  
generate a profit loss of channel that higher than 25%. Therefore, in the following subsections, we analyze four  
sharing contracts to investigate the optimal performance of a decentralized channel and compare them with the  
WP contract.  
1
Remark : The interaction between M and R in a decentralized channel under WP contract is often  
characterized by the power of decision making of the partners involved (Chakraborty et al., 2018). Three channel  
structures including: (i) M-led Stackelberg (MS), (ii) R-led Stackelberg (RS) and (iii) vertical Nash (VN) have  
been discussed in the literature (Ma et al., 2013). In the RS model, R is the Stackelberg leader, who anticipates  
M's reaction on wholesale price and green effort, and then decides on its retail price and marketing effort level. In  
the VN model, M's decisions and R's decisions are made independently. In our study, we address a channel  
where M is a Stackelberg leader (MS model).  
3.3. Decentralized channel under sharing contracts  
As the description of the sharing contracts in Section 2, the sequence of events under the sharing contracts is  
as follows: In the first step, both firms negotiate a sharing fraction . Then, in the second step, M decides the  
retail price, the product’s greening level and chooses a stocking quantity equal to demand to maximize his own  
profit. In the third step, R decides only on the marketing effort level to obtain her own profit maximization.2  
Therefore, after the sharing fraction was chosen, the behavior of M and R under the sharing contracts can be  
described by using M-led Stackelberg game setting where M as the leader and R as follower. Then, the  
Stackelberg game corresponding to each sharing contract can be expressed as follows:  
Contract  
Stage 1  
Stage 2  
max = (푝 − )(1 − )퐷 − 2/2  
max = (푝 − )퐷 − 휂푒2/2  
RP  
,  
max 푃푀 = (푝 − )(1 − )퐷 − (1 )휂푒2/2 2/2  
max 푃푀 = (푝 − )퐷 − 휂푒2/2  
RPM  
RPG  
,  
2
max 푃퐺 = 푝 (1 − )퐷 − (1 ) /2  
max 푃퐺 = (푝 − )퐷 − 휂푒2/2 2/2  
(
)
,  
(
)
1 −   
2
max 푃푀퐺 = 푝 1 − 퐷 −  
휂푒2  
(
)(  
)
max 푃푀퐺 = (푝 − )퐷 − 휂푒2/2 2/2  
,  
RPMG  
(1 − )  
2  
2
We solve the games by backward induction. The equilibrium results are listed in Tables 2 and 3.  
Table 2. The optimal decisions for centralized and decentralized channel  
Models/Contract  
Centralized  
Retail price  
Marketing effort level (e)  
greening level (θ)  
(푎 − 푏)휂휅  
−훾2휅 + 2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2  
(푎 − 푏)(3푏휂 − 훾2)휅  
(푎 − 푏)훾휅  
−훾2휅 + 2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2  
(푎 − 푏)훾휅  
4푏휂휅 − 22휅 − 휂휆2  
(푎 − 푏)훼훾휅  
(푎 − 푏)휂휆  
−훾2휅 + 2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2  
(푎 − 푏)휂휆  
4푏휂휅 − 22휅 − 휂휆2  
(푎 − 푏)(1 − 훼)휂휆  
+  
WP  
RP  
+  
푏(4푏휂휅 − 22휅 − 휂휆2)  
(푎 − 푏)휂휅  
2훼훾2휅 + 2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2 + 훼휂휆2  
(푎 − 푏)휂휅  
−훾2휅 + 2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2 + 훼휂2  
(푎 − 푏)휂휅  
2훼훾2휅 + 2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2  
(푎 − 푏)휂휅  
+  
2훼훾2휅 + 2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2 + 훼휂휆2  
(푎 − 푏)훾휅  
−훾2휅 + 2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2 + 훼휂2  
(푎 − 푏)훼훾휅  
2훼훾2휅 + 2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2 + 훼휂휆2  
(푎 − 푏)(1 − 훼)휂휆  
−훾2휅 + 2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2 + 훼휂2  
(푎 − 푏)휆  
RPM  
RPG  
RPMG  
+  
+  
2훼훾2휅 + 2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2  
(푎 − 푏)훾휅  
−훾2휅 + 2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2  
2훼훾2휅 + 2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2  
(푎 − 푏)휂휆  
−훾2휅 + 2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2  
+  
−훾2휅 + 2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2  
386  
Dinh Anh Phan, Hoa T. L. Vo, Hong Quang Duong/ MICA 2018 Proceedings  
Table 3: M’s, R’s and channel’s profit under sharing contracts and WP  
Models/  
R's profit  
M’s profit  
Omitted  
Total profit  
Contract  
(푎 − 푏)2휂휅  
Centralized  
WP  
Omitted  
2(−훾2휅 + 2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2)  
(푎 − 푏)2휂(2푏휂 − 훾2)휅2  
2(4푏휂휅 − 22휅 − 휂휆2)2  
(푎 − 푏)2훼휂(2푏휂 − 3훼훾2)휅2  
(푎 − 푏)2휂휅  
푎 − 푏2휂휅(6푏휂휅 − 3훾2휅 − 휂휆2)  
(
)
2(4푏휂휅 − 22휅 − 휂휆2)  
2(4푏휂휅 − 22휅 − 휂휆2)2  
푎 − 푏휂휅( 2푏휂휅 − 휂휆 2훼 훾 휅 − 휂휆 − 훼 (훾 휅 + 휂휆 ))  
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
푎 − 푏2(1 − 훼)휂휅  
(
)
(
)
(
)
(
)
2(2훼훾2휅 − 2푏휂휅 + 휂휆2 − 훼휂휆2)2  
RP  
2(2훼훾2휅 − 2푏휂휅 + 휂휆2 − 훼휂휆2)2  
(푎 − 푏)2훼휂(2푏휂 − 훾2)휅2  
2(훾2휅 − 2푏휂휅 + 휂휆2 − 훼휂휆2)2  
(푎 − 푏)2훼휂휅(2푏휂휅 − 3훼훾2휅 − 휂휆2)  
−4훼훾2휅 + 4푏휂휅 − 2휂휆2 + 2훼휂휆  
푎 − 푏2(1 − 훼)휂휅  
22휅 + 4푏휂휅 − 2휂휆2 + 2훼휂휆2  
(푎 − 푏)2휂휅(훾2휅 + 휂(−2푏휅 + (− 1)22))  
2(훾2휅 − 2푏휂휅 + 휂휆2 − 훼휂2)2  
(푎 − 푏)2휂휅(−2훼훾2휅 − 훼22휅 + 2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2)  
(
)
RPM  
푎 − 푏2(1 − 훼)휂휅  
(
)
RPG  
2(2훼훾2휅 − 2휅 + 2))2  
−4훼훾2휅 + 4푏휅 − 22  
2(2훼훾2휅 − 2휅 + 2)2  
(푎 − 푏)2휂휅  
(1 − )(푎 − 푏)2휂휅  
(푎 − 푏)2휂휅  
RPMG  
2(−훾2휅 + 2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2)  
2(−훾2휅 + 2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2)  
2(−훾2휅 + 2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2)  
4. Analytical results for channel performance  
4.1. Bargaining power and cooperation  
The channel contract terms can be decided overwhelmingly by one of the parties (R or M) depending on their  
bargaining power. Therefore, in this section, we first investigate the case that the sharing fraction in each  
sharing contract is determined by R. In this case, R is the dominant player and offers a take-it-or-leave-it sharing  
contract to M. Conversely, when M has more bargaining power than that of R, he embodies the channel power  
and offers a take-it-or-leave-it sharing contract to R and stipulates a sharing fraction which maximizes his profit.  
In some cases, the negotiation between R and M could be made to allocate the cost of efforts and/or revenues  
between these two parties (Arda, 2017). Therefore, we also investigate the cases where the sharing fraction is  
determined through the negotiation between R and M. In particular, we use the bargaining structure proposed by  
Nash to determine the optimal sharing fraction in this scenario. In a Nash bargaining game, two players have  
equal power and cooperatively decide on how the surplus generated by their interaction should be divided  
between them. In the next subsection, we analyze the impact of bargaining power on channel member’s profit.  
4.2. The impact of bargaining power on the channel member’s profit  
From the results in the Table 3, is a function of sharing fraction (). By examining the sign of the  
functions /휕with the condition of > 0 that assure positive profits for each partner in the channel, we  
drive the impact of bargaining power on the profit of M and R though the selection of in each sharing contract.  
We summarize with the following proposition.  
Proposition 1. When M is the dominant player and embodies the channel power, the equilibrium level of  
sharing fraction j* which maximizes M’s profit in the sharing contract j are as follow: (1) In the RP contract: as  
푏 > 훾2/, 푅푃∗ = 0, otherwise, 푅푃∗ = 2푏휂/3훾2. (2) In the RPM contract: 푅푃푀∗ = 0. (3) In the RPG contract:  
as 휂 > 22휅/(2푏휅 − 휆2), 푅푃퐺∗ = 0, otherwise, 푅푃퐺∗ = (2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2)/3훾2. (4) In the RPMG contract;  
푅푃푀퐺∗ = 0.  
From Proposition 1, we makes the following observations: In the RP contract, as 푏 > 훾2/and M has more  
contractual power than R, he will choose a value of approaching zero to attain the highest profit. Conversely,  
when 푏 < 훾2/, M’s profit increases with for any in the range of (0, 2푏휂/3훾2). Thus, M chooses a value of  
approaching 2푏휂/3훾2 to attain the highest profit. (2) In the RPM contract: M’s profit always decreases in .  
Therefore, M achieves the highest profit if approaches zero. (3) In the RPG contract: as is higher than a  
threshold level, i.e., 휂 = 22휅/(2푏휅 − 휆2), the smaller the selection of , the more profits M gets. This implies  
that M obtains the highest profit if the value of approaches zero. Otherwise, M should raise the value of   
approach (2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2)/3훾2to attract the highest profit. (4) In the RPMG contract: M’s profit always  
decreases with . Therefore, M attains the highest profit if approaches zero.  
Proposition 2. When R is the dominant player and embodies the channel power, the equilibrium level of  
sharing fraction j* which maximizes R’s profit in the sharing contract j are as follow: (1) In the RP contract: as  
휅 > (3훾22 2푏휂휆2)/(4푏2 22휂), 푅푃∗ = 1, otherwise, 푅푃∗ = (22휂휅 − 푏휂휆2)/(4푏2휅 − 3훾22 +  
푏휂휆2). (2) In the RPM contract: as 휅 < 2, 푅푃푀∗ = (−훾2휅 + 2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2)/휂휆2, otherwise, 푅푃푀∗ = 1. (3) In  
the RPG contract: as 휂 = 4훾2휅/(2푏휅 − 휆2) then 푅푃퐺∗ = 1, otherwise, 푅푃퐺∗ = (2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2)/4훾2. (4) In  
the RPMG contract: 푅푃푀퐺∗ = 1.  
By Proposition 2, we show the impact of bargaining power on R’s profit with the following observations: (1)  
In the RP contract: as is higher than a threshold level, ie, 휅 > (3훾22 2푏휂휆2)/(4푏2 22휂), R’s profit  
increases with (0,1). This suggests that if R has more contractual power than M, she increases the value of   
387  
Dinh Anh Phan, Hoa T. L. Vo, Hong Quang Duong/ MICA 2018 Proceedings  
approaching one to attract the highest profit. This also means that R should incur most of the production costs  
and extract most of the channel sales to maximize her profit. By contrast, R attains the highest profit if   
approaches (22휂휅 − 푏휂휆2)/(4푏2휅 − 3훾22 + 푏휂휆2). (2) In the RPM contract: as is higher than a threshold  
level, i.e, 휅 = 2, R’s profit increases with (0,1), therefore, R increases the value of to approach one to  
attract the highest profit. Conversely, R raises to approach (−훾2휅 + 2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2)/휂2 to maximize her profit.  
(3) In the RPG contract: As is higher than a threshold level, i.e, 휂 = 4훾2휅/(2푏휅 − 휆2), R increases the value  
of to approach one to attract more profit. On the contrary, R raises to approach (2푏휂휅 − 휂휆2)/42to  
attain the highest profit. (4) In the RPMG contract: R’s profit always increases with the value of . Therefore, R  
attains the highest profit if approaches one.  
We next examine the case when the sharing fraction is endogenously determined by both R and M. By using  
the Nash bargaining structure in which M has the same bargaining power to that of R, we identify the optimal  
profit allocation schemes for the problem of 푎푥 . We summarize the equilibrium level of sharing  
fraction in the following proposition.  
Proposition 3. The equilibrium solution of sharing fraction j∗ to the Nash bargaining problem under the  
sharing contract are as follow: (1) In the RP contract: 푅푃∗ = 퐴 − 1 so that 푅푃∗(0, 2) where 퐴 =  
2
3
2
2
2
2
2
2
4
2
2
3
2
3
2
4
4
2
4
2
2
2
2
3
2
3
4
2
4
2
4
2
3
4
2
4
4
2푏훾 휂휅+4푏  
휅−3훾 휂휆  
28푏  
−40푏  
+16푏  
24푏훾  
휅휆 +28푏  
휅휆 −8푏  
휅휆 +9훾  
−12푏훾  
+4푏  
and 퐵 =  
. (2) In  
4
2
2
2
2
2
4
2
2
2
2
2
2
2(−3훾 휅+7푏훾 휂휅−3훾 휂휆 +푏휂  
)
(3훾 휅−7푏훾 휂휅+3훾 휂휆 −푏휂  
)
2
4
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2 4  
the RPM contract: 푅푃푀∗  
=
−훾 휅+2푏휂휅 − √훾 휅 −4푏훾 휂휅 +4푏 휂 휅 +훾 휂휅휆 −2푏휂 휅휆 +휂 휆 so that 푅푃푀(0, 1). (3)  
2
2
4
휂휆  
휂 휆  
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2 4  
2
2
2
4
2
2
2
2
2 2  
2푏훾 휂휅 −4푏  
+훾 휂휅휆 +4푏휂 휅휆 −휂  
(2푏휅+휆  
)
(7훾  
+5훾 휂휅(2푏휅+휆 )+휂 (2푏휅+휆 ) )  
In the RPG contract:  
푅푃퐺∗  
=
so that  
2
2
2
4
2
2
2
2
(6훾 휅−14푏휂휅+7휂휆  
)
(6훾 휅+7(2푏휅+휆 ))  
1
푅푃퐺∗(1 , 2). (4) In the RPMG contract: 푅푃푀퐺∗ = .  
4
3
2
Proposition 3 shows that when the level of sharing fraction is determined through bargaining, the R obtains at  
most 75 percent of channel’s gross profit if she undertakes all of her marketing cost and does not bear M’s  
upfront cost of greening investment. In the case that R shares the gross profit margin of channel and cost of  
marketing efforts with M, R undertake at most 50 percent of her marketing costs. By contrast, when R decides to  
bear a proportion of M’s upfront greening cost, she absorbs at least 25 percent and at most 67 percent of that. In  
the case that R and M share all of the marketing, greening investment and production costs, firms agree on that  
the channel profit is split equally.  
4.3. The impact of on the channel’s profit  
We further investigate the impact of negotiation between the R and M on the total profit of the channel. With  
this aim, similar to Cachon (2003), we define the efficiency of the decentralized channel with respect to the  
centralized channel, as the ratio of the channel's profit in the decentralized channel to that in the centralized  
channel, i.e., = /. By examining the sign of the functions = 휕()/휕with the conditions of  
> 0, we summarize the impact of on the profit of the channel in the decentralized system through the  
following results: (1) The decentralized channel with the RP contract generates the highest profit when is  
2
2
2
2푏훾 휂휅−훾 휂휆  
chosen at 푅푃  
=
2. Furthermore, the profit of the decentralized channel in the RP  
2
2훾 휅+2푏훾 휂휅−4훾 휂휆 +2푏휂 휆  
4
2
2
2
contract is always less than that of the centralized channel. (2) The channel efficiency of the RPM contract  
2
2
훾 휅−2푏휂휅+휂휆  
always decreases in , approaches one as approaches zero and approaches  
as approaches  
2
훾 휅−2푏휂휅  
one. (3) The decentralized channel with the RPG contract generates the highest profit when is chosen at  
2
2푏휂휅−휂휆  
푅푃퐺  
=
2. However, the profit of the decentralized channel under the RPG contract is always less  
2
2훾 휅+2푏휂휅−휂휆  
than that of the centralized channel. (4) The decentralized channel with the RPMG contract generates the same  
profit as that of the centralized channel and the channel efficiency of the RPMG contract does not depend on the  
selection of .  
From the above analysis, we observe that the channel efficiency is highest in the RPMG contract and the  
RPMG contract perfectly coordinates the channel while the RP, RPM and RPG contracts do not coordinate the  
channel. Note that when = 0 in the RPM contract, the channel efficiency is equal to one, thus RPM can lead a  
perfectly coordinated channel. However, M captures all the channel profits while R obtains zero profit in this  
situation. Therefore, R has no incentive to accept an RPM contract with the sharing fraction equal to zero.  
4.4. Channel cooperation and greening-performance  
The aim of the channel cooperation is to determine a channel profit allocation scheme among its members.  
However, both R and M are willing to accept the optimal profit allocation schemes only if it can generate more  
profits than those derived in a non-collaborative channel (i.e., in the WP contract). Let (, ̅) represent a  
Pareto-improving region where both members of channel earn higher profit in the sharing contract compared to  
388  
Dinh Anh Phan, Hoa T. L. Vo, Hong Quang Duong/ MICA 2018 Proceedings  
WP contract, i.e., 푗∗ > and 푗∗ > . Thus, both the R and M will be motivated to adopt the shairng  
contract when the sharing fraction was choosen within these values. In the propositions 4-7, we identify the  
upper (̅) and lower bounds () of the Pareto-improving region and investigate the greening performance level  
of channel in this region corresponding to each sharing contract.  
Proposition 4: In the RP contract:  
푅푃  
(1) When 푏 > 훾2/휂 and > 휅 then 푅푃 = 0.5푢 − ; ̅ = 0.5,  
1
1
3
2
2
4
2
2
4
2
2
2
2
(16푏 휂 휅 +2훾 휅휆 −훾 휂휆 +(푏휂휆 −4푏 휂휅)(2훾 휅+3휂휆 ))  
where 1 =  
,
6
2
3
4
4
2
2
2
2
2
2
4
4훾 휅 +푏휂 휆 +4훾 휂휅(2휆 −5푏휅)+훾 휂 (24푏 휅 −16푏휅휆 +휆 )  
2
2
2
2
2
2
4
3
2
2
2
2
2
2
4
(훾 −푏휂)(2훾 휅−4푏휅+) (3훾 휆 −16푏 휂휅 +8푏 휅(훾 휅+2휂휆 )−푏(8훾 휅휆 +5휂휆 ))  
and 1 =  
.
6
2
3
4
4
2
2
2
2
2
2
4
2
(4훾 휅 +푏휂 휆 +4훾 휂휅(2휆 −5푏휅)+훾 휂 (24푏 휅 −16푏휅휆 +휆 ))  
(2) 푅푃 > 푊푃 when 푅푃 < < ̅ and the conditions of part (1) are satisfied.  
푅푃  
Proposition 5: In the RPM contract:  
푅푃푀  
(1) When 푏 > 훾2/2and 휅 > 휅 then 푅푃푀 = 푢 + 푣 ; ̅  
= 0.5, where 2 = (4훾42 + 22휂휅(32 −  
2
2
2
2
2
2
4
2
4
2
2
8푏휅) + 휂 (16푏 휅 − 12푏휅휆 + 3휆 ))/2휂 휆 and 2 = ( 2훾 휅 − 4푏휅 + 2(4훾42 + 82휂휅(휆2 2푏휅) +  
(
)
2(16푏22 − 16푏휅휆2 + 54)))/48.  
푅푃푀  
(2) 푅푃푀 > 푊푃 when 푅푃푀 < < ̅  
and the conditions of part (1) are satisfied.  
2
2
2
2
2
2
4
2
2
(2푏휅−휆 )(16푏 휂휅 +4훾 휅휆 +휂휆 −8푏휅(훾 휅+휂휆 ))  
Proposition 6: In the RPG contract, let 3 =  
,
2
4
2
2
2
2
2
2
훾 휅(8훾 휅 +3휂 (휆 −4푏휅) +4훾 휂휅(3휆 −10푏휅))  
2
2
2
2
2
2
4
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2 4  
1
훾 휂 휆  
휂휆  
3 = (휆 −2푏휅) (2훾 휅−4푏휅+) (8훾 휅 +4훾 휂휅(휆 −6푏휅)+휂 (휆 −4푏휅) ), 1 = √(2푏휂−훾 )(훾 −푏휂)  
; and  
4
2
4
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
훾 휅 (8훾 휅 +3휂 (휆 −4푏휅) +4훾 휂휅(3휆 −10푏휅))  
4
4(훾 −푏휂)  
2
2
2
4
3 4  
1
휂휆  
2 = √−훾 휂 휆 −푏휂 휆  
, we have :  
2
3
2
4
(훾 −푏휂)  
4(훾 −푏휂)  
(1) When 2/< 푏 ≤ 52/2, 1 < 휅 ≤ 2 or when 푏 > 52/2, 휅 < 휅 < 2 then 푅푃퐺 = 0.5(푢3 −  
푅푃퐺  
푅푃퐺  
푣 ); ̅  
= 0.5(푢 + ). Otherwise, when 푏 > 훾2/, 휅 > then 푅푃퐺 = 0.5(푢 − 푣 ); ̅  
=
3
3
3
2
3
3
(22휅 − 2푏휂휅)/(4훾2휅 − 4푏휂휅 + 휂휆2).  
푅푃퐺  
(2) 푅푃퐺 > 푊푃 when 푅푃퐺 < < ̅  
and the conditions of part (1) are satisfied.  
Proposition 7: In the RPMG contract:  
2
2
2
2
(훾 −2푏휂)(훾 휅−2푏휂휅+휂휆 )  
(훾 −2푏휂)휅  
푅푃푀퐺  
(1) When 푏 > 훾2/2and 휅 > 휅 then 푅푃푀퐺  
=
; ̅  
and the conditions of part (1) are satisfied.  
(3) 푃푀퐺 = , 푒푃푀퐺 = 푒, 푃푀퐺 = 푝, 푅푃푀퐺 = (1 − )and 푃푀퐺 = for any 0 < < 1.  
=
.
2
2
2
2
2
(2훾 휅−4푏휂휅+휂휆 )  
2훾 휅−4푏휂휅+휂휆  
(2) 푅푃푀퐺 > when 푅푃푀퐺 < < ̅  
푅푃푀퐺  
Part 1 of Proposition 4-7 indicates that there exists a Pareto optimal solution under each sharing contract  
through which channel members can maximize their profits. We also observe from Part 1 of Proposition 4 and 6  
that in RP and RPG, a win-win scenario for both channel members can be reached only when the effect of price  
on the market demand is relatively high i.e., 푏 > 훾2/휂. By contrast, from Part 1 of Proposition 5 and 7, RPM  
and RPMG always bring the channel to such a scenario regardless of the impact of price on market demand. We  
can further observe from Part 1 of Propositions 4 and 5 that RP and RPM only reach the cooperation state if R  
shares less than 50% of the production cost with M. From Part 2 of Proposition 4-7, the collaboration through  
bargaining between R and M under sharing contracts achieves the winwin-win situation, namely, R and M earn  
more profit; the environment is less affected by the M’s production process. Moreover, part 3 of Proposition 7  
shows that the profit of channel in the RPMG can be maximized and that of M and R will be arbitrarily allocated  
based on each player’s bargaining power.  
5. Numerical analysis  
In this Section, we numerically illustrate our results and gain further insights. We fix the parameter values as  
follows: a=101, b=3, c=10, γ = 0.9, λ=1, =0.8 and =1.6. These parameter values have been chosen for two  
reasons. First, these values guarantee that the profit of the centralized channel is jointly concave in p, e, and ,  
hence, the optimal decision of retail price , marketing effort level , and product greening level exists and  
is unique. Second, the parameters of a, b, c satisfy that the market demand is positive when the retail price is  
equal to the production cost, i.e., p=c.  
5.1. The sharing contracts use the same sharing rule (original model)  
Table 4 gives the numerical example results for the optimal decisions and the profit of the centralized channel  
and the decentralized channel under WP. The results of two models serve as benchmarks for the evaluation of the  
performance of sharing contracts.  
389  
Dinh Anh Phan, Hoa T. L. Vo, Hong Quang Duong/ MICA 2018 Proceedings  
Table 4. The optimal decisions under centralized channel and WP  
w
p
q
e
E
m  
r  
c  
Model  
Centralized  
channel  
10.17  
2
26.27  
5
48.82  
5
18.30  
9
-
-
-
577.765  
1
22.62  
4
30.21  
8
22.78  
1
0.71  
5
4.746  
8.543  
269.572  
143.796  
413.368  
WP  
From Tables 4, the production quantity, the marketing effort and the greening effort level of the decentralized  
channel under WP are lower than those of the centralized channel. These results lead to a lower profit for whole  
channel under WP. We next compute M's and R’s optimal decisions and profit in the decentralized channel under  
sharing contracts corresponding to the values of in the range of [0.01, 0.99]. We present the results of jm, 푗  
and j in Table 5. Furthermore, we also present the optimal decision of M on product’s greening level in this  
table to verify whether the greening level of channel is improved in the cooperation state.  
Table 5. Computational results of original model  
RP  
RPM  
RPG  
E
RPMG  
E
m  
r  
E
m  
r  
E
m  
r  
m  
r  
0.01  
0.1  
0.2  
0.3  
0.4  
0.5  
0.6  
0.7  
0.8  
0.9  
0.99  
465.5  
433.3  
395.8  
356.1  
314.1  
269.6  
222.3  
172.0  
118.5  
61.3  
5.2  
0.81  
0.84  
0.87  
0.89  
0.90  
0.91  
0.92  
0.91  
0.89  
0.86  
0.82  
8.19  
7.63  
6.97  
6.27  
5.53  
4.75  
3.91  
3.03  
2.09  
1.08  
0.11  
571.2  
512.6  
449.3  
387.8  
327.9  
269.6  
212.8  
157.5  
103.7  
51.2  
6.6  
1.00  
1.00  
0.99  
0.99  
0.98  
0.96  
0.95  
0.93  
0.92  
0.90  
0.88  
10.06  
9.03  
7.91  
6.83  
5.77  
4.75  
3.75  
2.77  
1.83  
0.90  
0.09  
466.0  
438.6  
405.7  
370.1  
331.3  
288.9  
242.4  
191.1  
134.2  
71.0  
4.7  
0.81  
0.84  
0.87  
0.90  
0.92  
0.94  
0.96  
0.96  
0.96  
0.94  
0.91  
8.29  
572.0  
520.0  
462.2  
404.4  
346.7  
288.9  
231.1  
173.3  
115.6  
57.8  
5.8  
1.00  
1.00  
1.00  
1.00  
1.00  
1.00  
1.00  
1.00  
1.00  
1.00  
1.00  
10.17  
10.17  
10.17  
10.17  
10.17  
10.17  
10.17  
10.17  
10.17  
10.17  
10.17  
52.4  
64.2  
47.8  
8.58  
57.8  
104.7  
156.7  
208.1  
258.4  
307.2  
353.8  
397.6  
437.6  
469.3  
124.9  
182.2  
236.4  
287.6  
336.1  
381.9  
425.3  
466.4  
501.6  
97.3  
8.93  
115.6  
173.3  
231.1  
288.9  
346.7  
404.4  
462.2  
520.0  
572.0  
148.5  
201.3  
255.4  
310.4  
366.0  
421.2  
474.8  
520.2  
9.31  
9.72  
10.17  
10.67  
11.21  
11.82  
12.49  
13.17  
6.3  
5.1  
7.5  
5.8  
We display the results of and in Table 5 through Figure 1 to demonstrate that R’s profit increases and  
M’s profit decreases with sharing fraction in all the sharing contracts.  
RP  
RPM  
RPG  
RPMG  
1(a)  
1(b)  
Fig. 1. (a) M’s profit, (b) R’s profit changes with sharing fraction  
We next display the value of j in Table 5 through Figure 2 to evidence that the channel efficiency is concave  
in sharing fraction () under RP and RPM contracts whereas it decreases in under RPM contract and remains  
stable at one under RPMG contract. We can also determine the value of that maximizes the channel efficiency  
푅푃  
푎푥  
푅푃푀  
푎푥  
under each sharing contract. Namely, 퐸  
= 0.916 at =0.582, = 0.964 at =0.726 and 퐸  
approach one when approaches to zero. These numerical results demonstrate that the RP, RPM and RPG  
contracts cannot coordinate the channel while the RPMG contract perfectly coordinates the channel.  
390  
Dinh Anh Phan, Hoa T. L. Vo, Hong Quang Duong/ MICA 2018 Proceedings  
RP  
RPM  
RPG  
RPMG  
Fig. 2. changes with sharing fraction  
We further observe from Table 5 that if the beforehand negotiated is at 0.3, 0.4 and 0.5 respectively, >  
and > 푊푃. This means that both R and M earn greater profits under the sharing contracts than under  
WP if the sharing faction was chosen at 0.3, 0.4 and 0.5 respectively. Thus, the Pareto improvements can be  
achieved if the sharing fraction was chosen at these values. From Proposition 1-4, we can determine the exact  
value of in the Pareto-improving region which leads to a win-win outcome, namely, 푅푃(0.275, 0.5),  
푅푃(0.232, 0.5), 푅푃(0.291, 0.543) and 푅푃푀(0.249, 0.533). Moreover, from observing the value of  
column , we find that the greening performance of the channel under each sharing contract is higher than those  
in WP for all values within the Pareto-improving region. (For example, when =0.3, the greening level of  
product under RP, RPM, RPG and RPMG are 6.27, 6.83, 9.31 and 10.17 respectively. These levels of greening  
are higher than that under WP (i.e., 4.746).  
5.2. The sharing contracts with different sharing parameters for effort costs  
So far, our analysis results in original model depending heavily on the assumption that the firms use the same  
sharing rule for all costs. We now extend our analysis using different the sharing parameters for costs. We denote  
such a contract as (, , ) where [0, 1] is the fraction of the gross profit (i.e., the total revenue minus the  
production cost of sold stocks) that R receives, [0, 1] is the fraction of R’s marketing cost that R undertakes;  
and [0, 1] is the fraction of M’s greening effort costs which R agrees to share with M. Under this setting, the  
equilibrium results can be derived by following backward induction. However, we obtained complex results that  
is difficult to analytically following the same procedure used in Section 4. Thus, we use numerical methods to  
illustrate the Pareto-improving region for this case.  
The Pareto-improving region is plotted in Figure 3 (a) with respect to and for the RPM contract with  
differentiating between the sharing rule for gross profit share, , and the sharing rule for the Marketing cost, φ  
(i.e., the sharing contract as (, , 0)). Every pair (, ) in this region presents a feasible solution to the  
bargaining problem that leads to higher profits of both channel members. Similarly, Figure 3 (b) illustrates the  
Pareto-improving region with respect to and for the RPG contract with differentiating between the sharing  
rule for gross profit, , and the sharing rule for the greening effort cost, (i.e., the sharing contract as (, 1, )).  
Compared to the results of original model, we find that the use of different sharing coefficients will expand more  
the feasible region. However, the negotiable range values for gross profit sharing do not change significantly  
compared to the original model. This result implies that regardless of efforts cost sharing, the adoption of a  
cooperative program on efforts is never feasible when most of the gross profits go to either M or R. Further, M is  
willing to implement a cooperative program on marketing efforts only when R bears marketing cost higher than a  
threshold (i.e., 13,6%). Whereas, R is willing to implement a cooperative program on greening efforts only when  
R incurs greening investment cost lower than a threshold, about 80%. This result is quite intuitive; the increase in  
cost share borne by the partner leads a decrease in benefits for the party who handles the activities and makes the  
implementation of a cooperative program on efforts difficult to be feasible.  
391  
Dinh Anh Phan, Hoa T. L. Vo, Hong Quang Duong/ MICA 2018 Proceedings  
Fig. 3. The Pareto-improving region in the RPM (a), RPG (b) contract with different sharing parameters for  
effort costs  
6. Conclusions, limitations and Future Research  
6.1. Conclusion  
In this paper, we studied the channel collaboration issues through coordinating contracts on efforts invested in  
order to promote the market demand and reduce the negative environmental impact of the channel. We study a  
two-echelon channel wherein the upstream manufacturer is responsible for product greening, a downstream  
retailer undertakes marketing activities and the market demand is affected by retail price, R’s marketing and M’s  
greening effort. These complex settings represent a realistic business practices for firms dealing with channel  
collaboration issues for the different decisions impacting on the channel performance including not only the  
operational choices (quantity, price) and marketing decisions of the firms but also the sustainable channel  
management. Therefore, we integrate M’s greening and R’s marketing efforts into the sustainable coordination of  
channel and propose the coordination schemes for the channel through the combination of revenue-sharing and  
cost-sharing contracts under a VMI-CC system. Through analytical model, we first analyze the impact of power  
structure on the implementation of sharing contracts, as well as the economic and environmental aspects in the  
channel. We then prove that the cooperation between M and R in a VMI-CC via sharing contracts is beneficial to  
channel agents, leads to higher profitability and results in higher levels of the environmental performance. From  
managerial insights, the channel managers can increase the greening level of product to meet the expectations of  
consumers while optimizing their economic performances by adopting sharing contracts.  
6.2. Limitations and Future Research  
Although the proposed model provides some ideas about how a green channel can be managed in the sense of  
profit maximization, there exist still some limitations that can be tackled in future research. First, for simplicity  
of analysis the demand is assumed as deterministic linear in price. Future research may be developed by  
considering the case of stochastic demand. Second, we don't take the joint impact of marketing and greening  
effort on the consumers’ behavior into consideration. In contrast, prior researchers show that potential types of  
customer benefits resulting from environmentally friendly consumption (i.e, Self-benefit value and societal  
benefit value) that depends not only on the green investment cost but also the interactions between firms and  
customers through marketing strategy (i.e., advertising appeals for the product, Green and Peloza, 2014).  
Therefore, future research can examine the case that the elasticity of greening investment on the customers’  
preference depends on the marketing strategy (i.e., advertising level and advertising appeals). Third, our study  
considers a channel in which both M and R have sufficient budget to make any decisions, however, in the real  
world, the capital constraints are a great challenge for many firms. Therefore, it might be interesting to examine  
our sharing contracts in a green channel where the capital constraints exist. Finally, as another opportunity for  
future investigation, researchers can explore the cases of asymmetric information. For example, the cost of green  
product R&D is the private information of M whereas R can be more knowledgeable about the cost of exerting  
marketing effort and the demand.  
392  
Dinh Anh Phan, Hoa T. L. Vo, Hong Quang Duong/ MICA 2018 Proceedings  
References  
[1] Arani, H.V., Rabbani, M., Rafiei, H., (2016). A revenue-sharing option contract toward coordination of  
supply chains. International Journal of Production Economics. 178, 42-56.  
[2] Babbar, S., Behara, R.S., Koufteros, X.A., Huo, B., (2017). Emergence of Asia and Australasia in operations  
management research and leadership. International Journal of Production Economics. 184, 80-94.  
[3] Bhaskaran, S. R., & Krishnan, V., (2009). Effort, revenue, and cost sharing mechanisms for collaborative  
new product development. Management Science, 55 (7), 1152-1169.  
[4] Cachon, G.P., (2003). Supply chain coordination with contracts. In: de Kok, A.G., Graves, S.C. (Eds.),  
Handbooks in Operations Research and Management Science, vol. 11. Elsevier, Boston, 229340.  
[5] Chakraborty, A., Chatterjee, A. K., & Mateen, A., (2015). A vendor managed inventory scheme as a supply  
chain coordination mechanism. International Journal of Production Research, 53 (1), 1324.  
[6] Chakraborty, A., Mateen, A., Chatterjee, A. K., & Haldar, N. (2018). Relative Power in Supply Chains–  
Impact on Channel Efficiency & Contract Design. Computers & Industrial Engineering.  
[7] Chen, J. M., Lin, I. C., & Cheng, H. L., (2010). Channel coordination under consignment and vendor-  
managed inventory in a distribution system. Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation  
Review, 46 (6), 831-843.  
[8] Ghosh, D., Shah, J., (2015). Supply chain analysis under green sensitive consumer demand and cost sharing  
contract. International Journal of Production Economics. 164, 319-329. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2014.11.005.  
[9] Hsueh, C. F. (2015). A bi-level programming model for corporate social responsibility collaboration in  
sustainable supply chain management. Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation  
Review, 73, 84-95.  
[10]Krishnan, H., Kapuscinski, R., Butz, D. A. (2004). Coordinating contracts for decentralized supply chains  
with retailer promotional effort. Management Science 50 (1): 48-63.  
[11]Ma, P., Wang, H., & Shang, J., (2013). Contract design for two-stage supply chain coordination: Integrating  
manufacturer-quality and retailer-marketing efforts. International Journal of Production Economics, 146 (2),  
745-755.  
[12]Ma, P., Wang, H., & Shang, J. (2013). Supply chain channel strategies with quality and marketing effort-  
dependent demand. International Journal of Production Economics, 144(2), 572-581.  
[13]Peloza, J and Green, T., (2014) "Finding the Right Shade of Green: The Effect of Advertising Appeal Type  
on Environmentally Friendly Consumption". Journal of Advertising.  
[14]Qian, D., & Guo, J. E. (2014). Research on the energy-saving and revenue sharing strategy of ESCOs under  
the uncertainty of the value of Energy Performance Contracting Projects. Energy Policy, 73, 710-721.  
[15]Raj, A., Biswas, I., & Srivastava, S. K. (2018). Designing supply contracts for the sustainable supply chain  
using game theory. Journal of Cleaner Production, 185, 275-284.  
[16]Ru, J., & Wang, Y., (2010). Consignment contracting: Who should control inventory in the supply chain?.  
European Journal of Operational Research, 201 (3), 760-769.  
[17]Sancha, C., Gimenez, C., Sierra, V., (2016). Achieving a socially responsible supply chain through  
assessment and collaboration. Journal of Cleaner Production. 112, 1934-1947  
[18]Song, H., & Gao, X. (2018). Green supply chain game model and analysis under revenue-sharing  
contract. Journal of Cleaner Production, 170, 183-192.  
[19]Swami, S., & Shah, J. (2013). Channel coordination in green supply chain management. Journal of the  
Operational Research Society, 64(3), 336-351.  
[20]Wang, S. J., & Hu, Q. Y., (2011). Business models for 3C retailers: interactions of sales promotion and trade  
schemes. Journal of Management Science in China, 14 (4), 1-11.  
[21]Wang, Y., Jiang, L., & Shen, Z. J., (2004). Channel performance under consignment contract with revenue  
sharing. Management science, 50 (1), 34-47.  
[22]Wong, W. K., Qi, J., & Leung, S.Y.S., (2009). Coordinating supply chains with sales re-bate contracts and  
vendor managed inventory. International Journal of Production Economics, 120 (1), 151161.  
[23]Xiao, T., Yu, G., Sheng, Z., & Xia, Y., (2005). Coordination of a supply chain with one-manufacturer and  
two-retailers under demand promotion and disruption management decisions. Annals of Operations  
Research, 135 (1), 87-109.  
[24]Xiao, T., & Yang, D. (2008). Price and service competition of supply chains with risk-averse retailers under  
demand uncertainty. International Journal of Production Economics, 114(1), 187-200.  
[25]Yang, H., Luo, J., Wang, H., (2017). The role of revenue sharing and first-mover advantage in emission  
abatement with carbon tax and consumer environmental awareness. International Journal of Production  
[26]Yenipazarli, A. (2017). To collaborate or not to collaborate: Prompting upstream eco-efficient innovation in  
a supply chain. European Journal of Operational Research, 260(2), 571-587.  
393  
pdf 12 trang Thùy Anh 14/05/2022 1940
Bạn đang xem tài liệu "Designing coordinating contracts for the consignment channel: Integrating manufacturer-greening and retailermarketing efforts", để tải tài liệu gốc về máy hãy click vào nút Download ở trên

File đính kèm:

  • pdfdesigning_coordinating_contracts_for_the_consignment_channel.pdf